Close Search
 
MEDIA, JOBS & RESOURCES for the COMMON GOOD
Opinion  | 

Curiosity, Caution and Social Impact Bonds


24 February 2016 at 10:23 am
Tony Pietropiccolo AM
For supporters of social impact bonds, the model is hailed as a new way of funding social services, but they are not as simple as they first appear, writes Tony Pietropiccolo AM, Director Centrecare Inc.

Tony Pietropiccolo AM | 24 February 2016 at 10:23 am


0 Comments


 Print
Curiosity, Caution and Social Impact Bonds
24 February 2016 at 10:23 am

For supporters of social impact bonds, the model is hailed as a new way of funding social services, but they are not as simple as they first appear, writes Tony Pietropiccolo AM, Director Centrecare Inc.

There is an increasing interest in the social impact bond (SIB), or as some are preferring to call them, “pay for success”. The latter name is being used by some in response to the criticism that SIBs are not bonds as these are normally understood to be. Pay for success implies that government only pays when interventions are successful.

The concept behind SIBs is that private investors will contract with both government authorities and service providers to achieve specified and measurable social outcomes. The first of these arrangements was established in the United Kingdom as part of the Big Society agenda.
The conservative UK government was happy to support a SIB projected to minimise the recidivism rate at a prison in Peterborough. The program was expected to cost $US8 million over six years. The most recent information is that the program is struggling to meet its outcomes.

The number of SIBs in the world is still relatively small. The most recent figures, according to international social development group Instiglio in January 2016, show that there are 31 SIBs in design stage and 48 at implementation stage. The UK and the United States account for 66 per cent of the total number of SIBs in both the implementation and design stages. The number drops rapidly in Eurasia with only 15 SIBs and South America with only five. Australia has two in implementation stage and one in design phase.

SIBs arose primarily in response to the economic downturn and financial stress that resulted from the world financial crisis that began in 2008. Not for profits struggling to attract donors to their causes and cash impoverished governments looked for alternative sources of funding.
Cash-strapped governments quickly became sold on the concept that they can use private money from investors for preventive social programs – money the government will have to pay back only if the programs produce the desired measurable outcomes.

Recently the New South Wales Government announced that its Newpin SIB had successfully achieved its desired outcomes. Newpin is a service that provides intensive support to improve parenting and thereby reduce the number of children taken into care and retain family cohesion.

NSW Premier and Cabinet said it was a program with a solid evidence base and track record of successfully restoring children to their families.

The government announced that the Newpin program had achieved a cumulative restoration of 61.6 per cent compared to a baseline of 25 per cent. Consequently, the investors would receive a 7.5 per cent return in the first year and 8.9 per cent in the second. NSW has also established a $10 million Benevolent Society Bond to be delivered over a five year period.

An attempt in NSW to establish another SIB in regards to recidivism was abandoned. The decision not to proceed was based on the aggregate challenges and risks of the proposed model, including the evolving nature of the justice and corrective services policy environment.

For supporters of SIBs, the model is seen to be a new way of funding social services as it has the capacity to attract new capital for programs. They argue that by making outcomes the basis for financial reward, greater efficiency is achieved.

It is widely perceived that SIBs provide the impetus for innovation and achieve greater effectiveness due to the pressure to attain specified results. These perceived attributes are reflected in the reasons given by the NSW Government for its involvement with SIBs.

The government believes that SIBs will:

  • Shift the focus onto outcomes rather than outputs
  • Direct additional resources towards early intervention
  • Encourage innovation
  • Improve the evidence base
  • Ensure accountability and transparency

Non-Government Organisations may see SIBs as an opportunity to attract new funding streams, especially at a time when donations are down and government funding is questionable.

The possibility of long term contracts of five or more years is also an attraction. The financial risk to NGOs appears minimal as it is the investor’s money that is at risk if outcomes are not achieved.

A number of governments are interested and keen to promote the concept, especially at a time of budgetary constraint, as they see it as a way of attracting private investment into an area that has been traditionally their responsibility to fund.

They may see such funding as ultimately replacing their involvement in large tracts of social expenditure and help to achieve “small government”. It’s also a funding strategy that precludes immediate outlays of money. The fact that they only repay the investors’ outlay with an additional interest payment, if agreed outcomes are met, is an additional attraction. There is another upside for government in that even if agreed outcome levels aren’t achieved some social services are likely to have been delivered.

On first glance there would appear to be good reasons to support SIBs. However, SIBs are not as simple as they may at first appear and their effectiveness and relevance to the delivery of long-term social programs are not as clear as one might expect.

Their promise to governments of a cheaper and more effective alternative to traditional means of social service delivery is also yet to be confirmed. The desirability and effectiveness of SIBs is viewed by many as questionable with the outcomes publicised by their proponents being highly suspect and backed by little evidence.

The hope that such programs will be a cheap and relatively simple option for governments is dubious. If the SIB successfully reaches its outcome targets the government will need to repay the investor outlay with an additional return which, as has been mentioned above, can be substantial depending on contractual arrangements.

In the event that outcomes are not met there is the expectation that government will pay nothing.

However, the reality is that contractual arrangements of this type are often complex, with some contracts being as long as 200 pages, and a legal minefield. To expect that investors will simply walk away from such contracts without making every attempt to argue for the return of some if not all of their investment is stretching credibility.

Added to the possibility of governments needing to pay, with an additional return to investors, for successful SIBs are the indirect costs of such agreements. The NSW Government spent two years, at substantial cost, establishing the contract related to the Newpin SIB. Then federal social services minister Scott Morrison stated that the Australian Government intended investing $20 million to develop a framework for SIBs. In addition to government’s costs are those of both private investors and service providers as they prepare and negotiate such complex deals.

The administrative and legal expenses associated with establishing these projects, along with the cost for independent assessors and ongoing bureaucratic monitoring, are largely hidden and raise questions as to how advantageous to the taxpayer SIBs actually are. Kyle McKay, a policy analyst with the US State of Maryland’s General Assembly, recommended against the establishment of a SIB in regards to prisoner recidivism. His analysis concluded that “the costs [of the SIB] did not stack up”.

He believed that if the benefit of SIBs could not be justified in the area of justice then it was unlikely that they would be of value in regards to other, more unpredictable, areas of social need.

The attractive idea that SIBs bring additional, new capital for social programs is highly questionable. The reality is that governments will ultimately be funding any program that proves to be successful and pay an additional premium in the process. Consequently, this is not adding “new money” but simply creating a new process through which government pays for services.
That it doesn’t pay for an unsuccessful program is little consolation as the ultimate aim of governments becoming involved with SIBs ought not to be to save money or engage in a funding experiment but to create effective and efficient social services.

Saving money from ineffective service delivery is a waste of resources and time. That SIBs will provide capital for innovation is not supported by the facts. In every instance where a SIB has been implemented it has been based on the existence of an already proven, effective program. Investors are very unlikely to risk their money on unproven and “blue sky” ideas. The NSW Government provided investors involved in the Newpin project with attractive conditions to allay their reluctance to invest.

According to Social Ventures Australia, the Newpin bond will pay a minimum coupon of five per cent per annum over the first three years. The bond also provides the benefit of a degree of capital protection; during the first four years any loss of principal will be limited to 25 per cent and after the fourth year principal loss will be limited to 50 per cent.

These are not typical conditions for SIBs where investors are not generally guaranteed protection of their investment, irrespective of outcome. One can only presume that the NSW Government was willing to underwrite these benefits to ensure the establishment of their first SIB. This raises the issue of how far a government would be willing to go to make SIBs attractive to investors.

Governments are equally very cautious of taking on uncertain ventures. The NSW Government did not proceed with the proposed recidivism SIB because of the uncertain environment in which it was to be established.

Most NGOs would need substantial seeding money to be able to create new service responses that are proven enough to attract SIB investment. This is likely to mean that SIBs will remain primarily an avenue for funding for those few organisations strong enough to garner research and development money. Social interventions that have rigorous evidence of their effectiveness, enough to convince investors, government and service providers to engage in a complex contractual arrangement, would seem ripe for traditional government funding that avoids the difficulties and additional costs invariably associated with SIBs.

There is a presumption underlying all SIBs that they, of their very nature, are likely to be far more efficient and effective than current forms of funding. Supporters of SIBs propose that the involvement of private financiers seeking to protect and gain from their investments will create the conditions for efficient and productive service delivery. However, there is little hard evidence that this is so. The privatisation of childcare and the disastrous failure of ABC Learning Centres in 2007 demonstrates that successful and sustainable service delivery is not always associated with commercially backed social initiatives.

Over the years, there have been numerous research papers and reports that have shown the economic savings of government sponsored social programs. However, these have been unsuccessful in convincing treasury departments to adequately fund much needed social services.

The claim made by SIB advocates of greater cost efficiencies and better service results than current services have no credibility unless there is evidence through rigorous comparison with existing, effective government/philanthropically funded programs. Without such a thorough cost/benefit analysis there is no reason to believe that SIBs provide any financial and/or service advantage to taxpayers.

Finally, how are we to understand the place of SIBs in a country’s social service system? For now there are few examples of successful SIBs and it is too early to know whether or not they can play a significant role in the delivery of social programs.

There are considerations for government as SIBs have the potential to create additional costs for taxpayers than current funding regimes without necessarily achieving better outcomes. There would appear to be risks for government, investors and service providers due to the convoluted nature of SIB contracts and the complexity of social interventions.

It may be that SIBs at best, are suitable for programs that are easily controlled and quantifiable. Some have referred to these as the low hanging fruit of social services. However, it is difficult to see how SIBs could be used as a basis on which to build long-term, integrated and coordinated responses to societal needs. Given the specific and individual nature of SIBs, it is possible that a reliance on them as a means to achieve social change can further fragment a service system that suffers from significant compartmentalisation.

Governments have for many years, and for good reason, sought to better integrate and coordinate services. SIBs would appear to run counter to this intent. While SIBs may be able to occupy a niche in the full suite of social service approaches, there needs to be a high degree of caution in seeing them as a means to achieve social reform and development.

About the author: Tony Pietropiccolo AM is Director of Centrecare Inc. in Western Australia – a Catholic Not for Profit, community services organisation delivering professional counselling, support, mediation and training services. His experience in social services is extensive having been involved in both paid and voluntary positions for over 30 years and having served on many boards and committees during this period. (This article is an edited version from the original which can be found here.)


Tony Pietropiccolo AM  |  @ProBonoNews

Tony Pietropiccolo AM is Director of Centrecare Inc. – a Catholic not-for-profit community services organisation.


 Print

Get more stories like this

FREE SOCIAL
SECTOR NEWS


YOU MAY ALSO LIKE

Understanding Unconscious Bias

BrookerConsulting

Friday, 19th April 2024 at 9:00 am

Using technology to support Australians going through hard times

Ed Krutsch

Friday, 19th April 2024 at 9:00 am

Is Discrimination Alive and Well?

BrookerConsulting

Friday, 12th April 2024 at 9:00 am

Bridging borders through philanthropy

Ed Krutsch

Friday, 12th April 2024 at 9:00 am

pba inverse logo
Subscribe Twitter Facebook
×